Introduction
to Taxation
Government
plays an important role in most modern economies. In the Kenya, the role of
the
government extends from providing for national defense to providing social
security and
Medicare
to the elderly. In order to provide for these program and services, the
government
needs
revenues. The sources of the revenues comes from taxes that are paid for by
households.
In
this chapter, we’ll go over a quick overview of taxes and look at how taxes
affect economic
decisions.
A. Sources of Government Revenue
Taxes
has two parts: (1) a base and (2) rate structure.
The
base is the measure or value upon which a tax is levied. The base can be
measures such as income, sales purchases, home value, corporate profits, etc…
The tax rate structure is the
percentage
of the tax base that must be paid in taxes.
For
example if you pay 35% of your income in taxes, then your income is the tax
base, and 35% is the tax rate structure. The tax base can either be a stock
measure (property, inheritance) or a flow measure (income, sales
Government Revenue
major sources of government revenue in the Kenya over
time. The major sources of revenue are:
(1) Individual
Income Tax: This is the tax you are most familiar with. Individuals must
pay this tax by April 15. During the year the government withholds
a portion of each
paycheck as tax payments. Table 1 shows that individual income tax
has been and still is
the single largest component of federal revenue over time.
(2) Social
Insurance Taxes: These taxes are levied on income to pay for Social Security
(retirement fund for the elderly) and Medicare (health care for
the elderly). Note how
these taxes has increased over time. In 1960, social insurance
taxes comprised only about
16% of total revenues, by 2008 that amount had reached almost 35%
(3) Corporate
Taxes: The corporate tax is a tax levied on the earnings of corporations.
This tax was an important source of revenues in the mid-20th century,
but has become
less important over time. The existence of tax shelters, laws to stimulate
R&D, and
complex rules regarding taxing multinational corporations have all
led to a decline in the
importance of corporate taxes as a source of federal revenue.
(4) Other Taxes: The other sources of government revenue are relatively minor. Excise
taxes are taxes that are levied on the sale
of certain products such as gasoline, cigarettes,
alcohol, etc…Estate taxes (sometimes called the “death tax”)
are levied on estates of
individuals when they passed away. Custom duties are taxes
levied on goods imported
to the Kenya, such as foreign cars or wines. Combined, these
sources of federal
revenues accounted for only 6.6% of total revenues in 2008.
B. Types of Taxes
A tax can either be proportional, progressive or regressive.
(1) Proportional Tax (Flat Tax): A proportional tax is a
tax whose burden is the same rate
regardless of the income earned by the household. For example
under a proportional tax
system, if the income tax rate is 13%, then a household who earns
$10,000 will pay 13%
of the their income in taxes, while a household who earns $10
million will also pay 13%
of their income as taxes.
(2) Progressive Tax: A progressive tax is a tax that exacts
a higher percentage of income
from higher income households than from lower income households.
The current income
tax system in the Kenya is a progressive tax. For example, under a
progressive tax
system, a household that earns $10,000 would pay a 5% income tax
while a household
that earns $10 million would have to pay a 35% income tax.
(3) Regressive Tax: A regressive tax means that higher
income households pay less in taxes
as a percentage of their income than lower income families. Excise
taxes and retail sales
taxes are examples of regressive taxes.
Household Income Savings .
Illustrates how a retail or
consumption tax can be regressive. Suppose that tax reform
eliminates the income tax and imposes a national sales retail tax
of 5% on the purchase of all
goods. We have two families the Smiths and the Jones’. The Jones’
have an annual household
income of $100,000 while the Smiths are not so well off and earn
only $10,000. Suppose that
the Smiths have to spend all of their income to pay for basic
necessities such as food, shelter and
clothing and they have nothing left over to save (their saving
rate is 0%). The Jones’, on the
other hand, are able to save some of their income (their saving
rate is 30%). Thus the Jones’
total spending is $70,000 while the total spending for the Smiths’
is $10,000. If the retail tax is
5%, the Smiths will pay $500 in taxes while the Jones’ will pay
$3500 in taxes. As a percentage
of income, the Smith’s will pay a higher tax rate ($500/$10,000 =
5%) than the Jones’
($3500/$100000 = 3.5%). Thus a sales tax is a regressive tax.
C. Marginal vs. Average Tax Rates
Average tax rate is the total amount of tax paid
divided by income.
Example: Suppose that your total income is $50,000 and that you
pay $10,000 in taxes. Your
average tax rate is $10,000/$50,000 = 20%.
Marginal Tax Rate is the tax rate that you pay on any additional income you earn.
Example: Suppose that you have a part-time job that earns you an
extra $1000 a year. If you
have to pay an additional $250 in taxes on that extra $1000 in
income, then we say that the
marginal tax rate is 25%.
Marginal tax rates are important because they play a key
determinant in household decisions on
working extra hours and/or making contributions to charity. In
order to see why marginal tax
rates determines these factors we have to look at how our current
tax system works.
The taxes are marginal taxes.
Let’s work through a numerical example to see how taxes are paid.
Suppose that Stacy earned
$60,000 in income last year (before paying any taxes). Taxpayers are
allowed to make
deductions (reductions in their income) in the form of standard
deductions ($5350) and in
personal exemptions ($3400). These deductions lowers the amount of
taxable income.
(
Before Tax Income = $60,000
Standard Deduction= -$5,350
Personal Exemption = -$3,400
Taxable Income After Deductions = $51,250
Now we can see how
marginal tax rate can affect decisions to work and to
contribute to charity.
(1) Incentive to work: If Stacy’s decides to take a second
job, her income from that second
job will be taxed at the 25% bracket. At that rate, Stacy may
decide it might not be worth
it to work that second job. If the marginal tax rate is very high,
it might provide a
disincentive for workers to work overtime hours or work the second
job.
(2) Incentive to contribute to charity: One of the features
of charitable giving is that the
donations are tax-deductable. That is if you give $1000 to your
local church, you may
deduct that contribution from your income and thus lower your
taxable income. For
example, suppose that Stacy also contributed $2000 to the Red
Cross last year. We
would add that contribution to her standard deduction and thus
lower her income after
deductions to $49,250. Stacey has to pay less in taxes due to the
charitable donation.
She pays 25% on now $17,400 (instead of $19,400) at 25%. The taxes
she must pay on
her last slice of her income is now $4,350. Stacey has saved $500
in taxes owed. High
marginal tax rate would increase the incentive for individuals to
contribute to charity so
they can take a higher deduction.
II. Tax Incidence: Who Pays?
When the government passes tax laws, the laws clearly indicates
who has the responsibility to
pay the tax. For example, an excise tax on cigarettes might impose
a tax that cigarette
manufacturers must pay per pack of cigarettes sold. However, as we
will soon see, the burden of
a tax might not always be borne by those who the law saws have a
responsibility to pay for it.
For
most taxes, the burden of payments is often shifted, either directly or
indirectly to others.
A.
Tax-Shifting: Tax on Producers
Let
us use our supply and demand framework to look at how taxes affect economic
behavior and
how
the burden of taxes can shift from one party to another. Figure 1 below looks
at the market
for
12 pack of Cokes. Initially, the market supply and market demand curves
intersected at Point
A.
Thus the market equilibrium price is at $3 while the market equilibrium
quantity was at 900
packs of
sodas.
Tax Incidence and
Elasticity
As
we have seen both graphically and algebraically, an increase in taxes will
result in the tax
burden
being shared by consumers and producers. If a tax is placed on producers, how
much of
the
tax can be shifted forward on to the consumers? The answer depends on the price
elasticity
of
demand for the taxed good. If the demand for the taxed good is very inelastic
(in other words
consumers
are not very responsive to price changes) then consumers will pay the large
bulk of
the
tax.
Consider
the example of the extreme case of a good with perfectly inelastic demand.
Recall that
if
a good has perfectly inelastic demand, consumers will not alter the amount
purchase no matter
what the
price of the good. In other words the demand curve is vertical.
Taxes and Inefficiency
A.
Calculating Deadweight Loss with Taxes
In
our two examples where we looked at tax shifting, the one thing both had in
common was
that
the equilibrium quantity decreases after a tax is imposed. There is an
underproduction of
the
good compared to the original socially optimal level. We know from Chapter 4
that
when
there is underproduction, economic inefficiency will result in the form of
deadweight
losses.
Let’s calculate the deadweight loss that would result from a tax.
Figure
5 looks at a situation where a tax will be imposed on firms. Without a tax, the
equilibrium
price will equal $10 and the equilibrium quantity will be 30,000. Given this
initial
equilibrium, let us calculate (a) consumer surplus, (b) producer surplus, and
(c) total
surplus.
Deadweight Losses and
Elasticity
As
we saw earlier, the price elasticity of demand is important in determining the
ability of the
firm
to shift the tax burden to consumers. If demand for a good is relatively
inelastic, the firm is
able
to shift a majority of the tax burden to consumers, while if the demand for a
good is
relatively
elastic, the firm will not have the ability to shift much of the tax to
consumers. It turns
out
that price elasticity of demand can also be used to determine the size of the
excess burden or
deadweight
loss that will occur if a tax is imposed. To see why, let us recall why
deadweight
loss
exist in the first place.
The
presence of a deadweight loss means that society is either under-producing or
overproducing
the
socially optimal level of output. In the case of a tax, fewer output will be
produced
than otherwise would have been in the absence of a tax. The loss to society is
the loss
in
consumer and producer surplus from units of good that should have been produced
but was
not
due to the tax.
With
that in mind, let us consider what price elasticity of demand can tell us about
deadweight
loss.
Let us consider two cases: (1) relatively elastic demand and (2) relatively
inelastic demand
(1)
Relatively Elastic Demand: By definition, if a good has elastic demand, that
means that
consumers
are very responsive to changes in price. An increase in taxes
will cause an increase
in
price that consumers have to pay (unless demand is perfectly elastic).
Consumers will respond
to
this increase in price by cutting back their consumption of the good and the
quantity will fall
drastically.
As a result, equilibrium quantity after the tax will be significantly lower
than the
quantity
that was consumed prior to the tax. Since there is significantly less goods
being
consumed
than what is socially optimal, there will be a greater loss to society. The
loss to
society
will be all the units of good that would have been produced and consumed in the
absence
of
the tax. In short, the more responsive the consumer
behavior to a change in price (the
more
elastic the demand), the greater the deadweight loss (or excess burden).
Relatively
Inelastic Demand: Consider the opposite case where consumers are generally
irresponsive to changes in price. An increase in price that consumers pay due to a tax will
lower
the
quantity demanded, but not very much. Since the quantity demanded will be very
close to
the
initial pre-tax level of quantity demanded, the “lost production” will be
small. Since the new
equilibrium
quantity is close to the initial socially optimal level of output, the
deadweight loss or
excess
burden will be small (especially compared to the case of elastic demand).
Figure 7
illustrates
the case of inelastic demand. A good that has inelastic demand will have a
demand
curve
that is relatively steep. As we can see in Figure 7, new equilibrium quantity
that results
from
the tax increase is lower than initial equilibrium, but it’s not far from the
initial level. As a
direct
result the area of the deadweight loss is small. If the demand for the good has
inelastic
demand,
then the deadweight loss or excess burden will be relatively small
No comments:
Post a Comment